Executive Summary
Once upon a time there was a very boring thing called the land-line telephone with about one rotary telephone per household. Then, land-line telephone services prices started to go down while incomes continued to rise and U.S. consumers started to buy more than one telephone per household, perhaps helped by the growing influence and the coming of age of the Baby Boom generation. After that, telephone consumption by households became a bit more interesting as households got the touch-tone phone, call waiting, then caller I.D., etc. When consumers started to get excited about the changes in the land-line telephone, the market transformed radically with the introduction of the cellular telephone and then with the introduction of the Internet and the smart phone. Since then, the consumer market for telephones has never looked back. The rest is history: a good history for cellular telephone consumption and a not so bright history for land-line telephone consumption.
In this report we take a look at what has happened over the last several decades to personal consumption expenditures (PCE) of land-line telephone service and cellular telephone service from the perspective of the U.S. consumer. Our conclusion is that land-line telephone services consumption is bound to get close to zero or to hit a lower bound that may not be much different from zero, especially if the industry can keep the bundling strategy together. However, while older generations may be enticed by the bundling strategy from the industry, it is not clear that newer generations may have the same predisposition to this strategy.1
Furthermore, consumers that hold to their land-line telephone services seem to accept, at least for now, paying more and more for land-line telephone services, for both local calls as well as longdistance calls as reflected by the ever increasing price for those two services while the price for cellular phone services has continued to decline. However, the downward trend for the consumption of land-line telephone services does not augur a promising future for that strategy. At the same time, we point to statistical relationships that tend to point to price sensibilities that have made possible such pricing strategies.
Some Americans are Still Holding Tight to Their Land-Lines2
The telephone communication industry has seen an impressive transformation over the last several decades with consumers massively picking to use a cellular phone instead of the more "traditional" land-line telephone, according to a view from analyzing PCE data. In this report we look at the consumption of land-line and cellular telephone services over time by analyzing data from personal consumption expenditures. That is, we look at demand for cellular and land-line telephone services from the consumer point of view and will not attempt to untangle or even attempt to propose changes in industry strategy of any kind. Having said this, we may, at different points in the report, infer some already known and heavily researched facts regarding the trends in the telephone industry.
By looking at telephone service consumption from PCE data, both from land-lines as well as cellular telephone services, it is clear that traditional land-line telephone service consumption continues to unravel. That is, according to data from PCE over the last several decades' consumers continue to shun land-line telephone services in favor of cellular telephone services at a pace that, if sustained into the future, would imply that consumers will stop consuming land-line telephone services during the next several decades.
It is possible, however, that land-line consumption levels probably have a lower bound (see Footnote 1), that is, they may never go to zero, but this lower bound is probably very low and is probably a consequence of some of the characteristics of today's consumption of land-line telephone services. One of these characteristics is the fact that many homes across the country are also used as businesses and households may keep their land line so they are able to send/receive faxes or use the land-line telephones as office phones for their home business. However, if those land-lines used for business purposes are reported as only business expenditures, then those land-lines will not be included in the PCE data. If consumers, on the other hand, report their land line usage as 50 percent for personal use and 50 percent (or a different combination between them) for business purposes, then 50 percent of this consumption of land-line telephone services corresponds to PCE land-line services consumption.
It is also possible that the "bundling" strategy by the cable industry may have slowed down the downward path or the "demise" of land-line telephone service consumption. However, the longterm trend continues to be that of a slow and protracted disappearance of land-line telephone service consumption (see Figure 1 above). It may also be the case that Americans are holding to land-line telephone services so they can make long-distance calls, as real consumption of long-distance services by land-line telephone holders is low but has stabilized during the last several years (see Figure 2 above).
Portability and Functionality of Cell Phones versus Land-Lines
Perhaps one of the most important characteristics of the early-days' cellular telephone versus a land-line telephone was the former's portability. However, as cellular phone technology advanced it became clear that another, perhaps even more important characteristic, was the irruption of the Internet and the introduction of the smart-phone a little more than 20 years ago. Looking back, the history of the smart phone probably had different paths in two different markets. For the business community, smart phone usage took off after the introduction of the BlackBerry in 2003, which made business e-mail and some internet connectivity accessible for business purposes.3 However, for the personal consumer/household market the product that pushed the smart phones into the mainstream was the launch of the iPhone in 2007.4 Today, these different paths are not as clear cut as they used to be as any original differences between business and personal/household use of smart phones seems to have been blurred by the evolution of the smart phone and the increasingly similar needs among business people and personal/household customers. That is, what were very different markets at the beginning of this century has given way to strategies that include BYOD (Bring your own device) policies within the business community.
However, the PCE data that we are using to look at the land-line telephone service versus cellular telephone service usage only include phone usage for personal/household usage. Having said this, it is probably almost impossible today to be sure that the PCE data used here do not include some part of business telephone usage, especially in the cellular telephone consumption market side as many firms, as we said before, have been moving to some type of BYOD system by which workers use their personal cellular telephones for conducting business and in many cases do not get reimbursed by the firms for the partial use of those personal cellular telephones.
Who Needs (Costly) Land-Line Telephone Services Anyway?5
This is, perhaps, the question many firms that market and sell land-line telephone services asked themselves when cellular telephone service and internet consumption started to outpace land-line telephone service consumption. And the answer was probably the following: very few, which meant that selling land-line telephone services wasn't going to be a good business anymore. However, with the advent of the Internet and help from very fluid mergers and acquisitions the industry has been transformed to one that sells not only land-line telephone services but also internet services, cable TV services, etc. The addition of these services has allowed the industry to continue to sell land-line telephone services by, as we argued above, "bundling" telephone services with the other services together so customers can get a "better price," i.e., lower price for the other services, but especially for internet access.
Furthermore, this strategy has also allowed these companies to use a very different price strategy than the one being used by companies that sell cellular telephone services (see Figure 3 above). That is, this strategy has allowed them to keep increasing prices for land-line telephone services, on both local as well as long-distance service charges, compared to what has happened to services sold by companies that sell cellular telephone services. That is, our analysis confirms that there is more competition for cellular telephone services than for land-line telephone services, which is probably a consequence of the bundling strategy followed by land-line telephone service providers.
Thus, although consumption of land-line telephone services has continued to decline, it seems that the bundling strategy has been working for these companies as they have continued to increase prices on those services. That is, prices for land-line telephone services have been going up unabated over the last several decades and this has helped to prevent expenditures from landland telephone services, both local charges as well as long-distance charges, from completely collapsing.
The changes that have occurred during the last several decades in this industry are impressive, with the largest component of expenditures generated by PCE consumption of these services coming from the consumption of internet access (almost 50 percent versus less than 10 percent in 1999). Cable & satellite services come in second, with about 35 percent, and then domestic calls services charges (12 percent versus more than 35 percent in 1999) and land-line long distance services charges (only about 5 percent versus a bit more than 30 percent in 1999), figure 5.
However, at this rate, as we said before, the durable life of land-line telephones is in peril. Furthermore, how much more can consumers continue to experience land-line telephone services price increases without reacting more forcefully and quitting these services altogether? Perhaps customers know that this is the "cost" to pay for having internet services and they accept it as it. However, our guess is that there is a younger generation that doesn't care for land-line telephone services and once they become the majority then land-line telephone services will disappear.
Thus, if land-line telephone consumption finally goes to zero in the not-so-distant future then this pricing strategy will have to change very fast, with customers experiencing a transition period in which internet access prices (or other services prices like cable TV services) will probably need to increase so that these companies can recapture revenues lost by not being able to charge for landline telephone services consumption, both domestic and long-distance.
Once again, we are not telephone industry analysts so we leave the alternative scenarios of how any transitions may happen to those that know. We are only looking at the industry indirectly by using personal consumption expenditure data over time and although the picture does not look good for companies selling land-line telephone services, the alternatives these companies may need to use to adapt to the new consumer scenario may be easier and much simpler than what it is implied by just looking at PCE data.
That is, the merger and acquisition process that continues to occur within this industry and between this industry and other, highly interrelated industries is a clear example of how these companies are preparing for, what today seems to be, the probably inevitable disappearance of consumption of land-line telephone service.
Econometric Results and Conclusions6
In order to look at some of the statistical relationships between these different services and try to make sense of what has been happening from the consumer side, we ran several regression equations on land-line as well as cellular telephone consumption. The results shed some light on some of the characteristics of the consumption market for these services.
Our econometric results show that land-line telephone services consumption is slightly responsive to its own price and has the correct sign, i.e., if there is an increase in price for the land-line telephone service then the quantity demanded of land-line telephone services declines. However, this responsiveness is very low; in economic parlance, land-line telephone services consumption is highly inelastic. This could explain why land-line telephone services prices have continued to go up over the years and quantity consumed of land-line telephone services has gone down but at a very slow pace. At the same time, this low sensitivity to price increases gives some credence to the ever-increasing price strategy implemented by the industry over the last several years and supports the bundling strategy chosen.
Meanwhile, although cellular telephone services consumption is also not very responsive to price changes, it is more responsive to increases in cellular telephone services prices than land-line telephone services. Furthermore, land-line local telephone services consumption is not responsive to the price of cellular phone services, according to our econometric results. At the same time, land-line telephone service consumption is not responsive to the price of cable TV services and/or to the price of internet access services. We measured this relationship just to confirm the relationship between land-line telephone services and cable TV and internet access services as part of the bundling strategy by land-line telephone service firms.
However, we found that consumption of cellular telephone services is somewhat responsive to the price of internet access services. That is, the higher the price of internet access services the lower the demand for cellular telephone services consumption. This is intuitively appealing for a consumer concerned with keeping their cellular telephone bill in check. It is also a very appealing characteristic for an industry that, until recently, charged more for more usage of the cellular telephone capabilities in terms of bandwidth.
All these results point to a very dismal future for land-line telephone consumption. The fact that the price of land-line telephone services continue to increase implies that, in the long run, telephone service consumption will likely approach zero. Having said this, we indicated that this may not be completely true if some of the characteristics of the market remain as effective as they are today, i.e. bundling. That is, we understand that consumption of land-line telephone services may have a lower bound that may differ from zero.
We did not measure, however, the effect of the new generations in terms of their attitude against the land-line telephone consumption, i.e., the attitudes of millennials for land-line telephone services consumption. The truth is that the new generations don't seem to need land-line telephones because cellular telephones and the Internet provide all of the needs for their generation. Thus, even if there is a lower bound for the consumption of land-line telephone services, and this lower bound is different from zero, generational characteristics may push consumption of land-line below that lower bound created by the industry with the bundling strategy. Again, we did not control for this variable but we think that it is an important aspect and difference between previous generations and the current ones.
Recently, the stock market has experienced high levels of volatility. If you are thinking about participating in fast moving markets, please take the time to read the information below. Wells Fargo Investments, LLC will not be restricting trading on fast moving securities, but you should understand that there can be significant additional risks to trading in a fast market. We've tried to outline the issues so you can better understand the potential risks. If you're unsure about the risks of a fast market and how they may affect a particular trade you've considering, you may want to place your trade through a phone agent at 1-800-TRADERS. The agent can explain the difference between market and limit orders and answer any questions you may have about trading in volatile markets. Higher Margin Maintenance Requirements on Volatile Issues The wide swings in intra-day trading have also necessitated higher margin maintenance requirements for certain stocks, specifically Internet, e-commerce and high-tech issues. Due to their high volatility, some of these stocks will have an initial and a maintenance requirement of up to 70%. Stocks are added to this list daily based on market conditions. Please call 1-800-TRADERS to check whether a particular stock has a higher margin maintenance requirement. Please note: this higher margin requirement applies to both new purchases and current holdings. A change in the margin requirement for a current holding may result in a margin maintenance call on your account. Fast Markets A fast market is characterized by heavy trading and highly volatile prices. These markets are often the result of an imbalance of trade orders, for example: all "buys" and no "sells." Many kinds of events can trigger a fast market, for example a highly anticipated Initial Public Offering (IPO), an important company news announcement or an analyst recommendation. Remember, fast market conditions can affect your trades regardless of whether they are placed with an agent, over the internet or on a touch tone telephone system. In Fast Markets service response and account access times may vary due to market conditions, systems performance, and other factors. Potential Risks in a Fast Market "Real-time" Price Quotes May Not be Accurate Prices and trades move so quickly in a fast market that there can be significant price differences between the quotes you receive one moment and the next. Even "real-time quotes" can be far behind what is currently happening in the market. The size of a quote, meaning the number of shares available at a particular price, may change just as quickly. A real-time quote for a fast moving stock may be more indicative of what has already occurred in the market rather than the price you will receive. Your Execution Price and Orders Ahead In a fast market, orders are submitted to market makers and specialists at such a rapid pace, that a backlog builds up which can create significant delays. Market makers may execute orders manually or reduce size guarantees during periods of volatility. When you place a market order, your order is executed on a first-come first-serve basis. This means if there are orders ahead of yours, those orders will be executed first. The execution of orders ahead of yours can significantly affect your execution price. Your submitted market order cannot be changed or cancelled once the stock begins trading. Initial Public Offerings may be Volatile IPOs for some internet, e-commerce and high tech issues may be particularly volatile as they begin to trade in the secondary market. Customers should be aware that market orders for these new public companies are executed at the current market price, not the initial offering price. Market orders are executed fully and promptly, without regard to price and in a fast market this may result in an execution significantly different from the current price quoted for that security. Using a limit order can limit your risk of receiving an unexpected execution price. Large Orders in Fast Markets Large orders are often filled in smaller blocks. An order for 10,000 shares will sometimes be executed in two blocks of 5,000 shares each. In a fast market, when you place an order for 10,000 shares and the real-time market quote indicates there are 15,000 shares at 5, you would expect your order to execute at 5. In a fast market, with a backlog of orders, a real-time quote may not reflect the state of the market at the time your order is received by the market maker or specialist. Once the order is received, it is executed at the best prices available, depending on how many shares are offered at each price. Volatile markets may cause the market maker to reduce the size of guarantees. This could result in your large order being filled in unexpected smaller blocks and at significantly different prices. For example: an order for 10,000 shares could be filled as 2,500 shares at 5 and 7,500 shares at 10, even though you received a real-time quote indicating that 15,000 shares were available at 5. In this example, the market moved significantly from the time the "real-time" market quote was received and when the order was submitted. Online Trading and Duplicate Orders Because fast markets can cause significant delays in the execution of a trade, you may be tempted to cancel and resubmit your order. Please consider these delays before canceling or changing your market order, and then resubmitting it. There is a chance that your order may have already been executed, but due to delays at the exchange, not yet reported. When you cancel or change and then resubmit a market order in a fast market, you run the risk of having duplicate orders executed. Limit Orders Can Limit Risk A limit order establishes a "buy price" at the maximum you're willing to pay, or a "sell price" at the lowest you are willing to receive. Placing limit orders instead of market orders can reduce your risk of receiving an unexpected execution price. A limit order does not guarantee your order will be executed -" however, it does guarantee you will not pay a higher price than you expected. Telephone and Online Access During Volatile Markets During times of high market volatility, customers may experience delays with the Wells Fargo Online Brokerage web site or longer wait times when calling 1-800-TRADERS. It is possible that losses may be suffered due to difficulty in accessing accounts due to high internet traffic or extended wait times to speak to a telephone agent. Freeriding is Prohibited Freeriding is when you buy a security low and sell it high, during the same trading day, but use the proceeds of its sale to pay for the original purchase of the security. There is no prohibition against day trading, however you must avoid freeriding. To avoid freeriding, the funds for the original purchase of the security must come from a source other than the sale of the security. Freeriding violates Regulation T of the Federal Reserve Board concerning the extension of credit by the broker-dealer (Wells Fargo Investments, LLC) to its customers. The penalty requires that the customer's account be frozen for 90 days. Stop and Stop Limit Orders A stop is an order that becomes a market order once the security has traded through the stop price chosen. You are guaranteed to get an execution. For example, you place an order to buy at a stop of $50 which is above the current price of $45. If the price of the stock moves to or above the $50 stop price, the order becomes a market order and will execute at the current market price. Your trade will be executed above, below or at the $50 stop price. In a fast market, the execution price could be drastically different than the stop price. A "sell stop" is very similar. You own a stock with a current market price of $70 a share. You place a sell stop at $67. If the stock drops to $67 or less, the trade becomes a market order and your trade will be executed above, below or at the $67 stop price. In a fast market, the execution price could be drastically different than the stop price. A stop limit has two major differences from a stop order. With a stop limit, you are not guaranteed to get an execution. If you do get an execution on your trade, you are guaranteed to get your limit price or better. For example, you place an order to sell stock you own at a stop limit of $67. If the stock drops to $67 or less, the trade becomes a limit order and your trade will only be executed at $67 or better. Glossary All or None (AON) A stipulation of a buy or sell order which instructs the broker to either fill the whole order or don't fill it at all; but in the latter case, don't cancel it, as the broker would if the order were filled or killed. Day Order A buy or sell order that automatically expires if it is not executed during that trading session. Fill or Kill An order placed that must immediately be filled in its entirety or, if this is not possible, totally canceled. Good Til Canceled (GTC) An order to buy or sell which remains in effect until it is either executed or canceled (WellsTrade® accounts have set a limit of 60 days, after which we will automatically cancel the order). Immediate or Cancel An order condition that requires all or part of an order to be executed immediately. The part of the order that cannot be executed immediately is canceled. Limit Order An order to buy or sell a stated quantity of a security at a specified price or at a better price (higher for sales or lower for purchases). Maintenance Call A call from a broker demanding the deposit of cash or marginable securities to satisfy Regulation T requirements and/or the House Maintenance Requirement. This may happen when the customer's margin account balance falls below the minimum requirements due to market fluctuations or other activity. Margin Requirement Minimum amount that a client must deposit in the form of cash or eligible securities in a margin account as spelled out in Regulation T of the Federal Reserve Board. Reg. T requires a minimum of $2,000 or 50% of the purchase price of eligible securities bought on margin or 50% of the proceeds of short sales. Market Makers NASD member firms that buy and sell NASDAQ securities, at prices they display in NASDAQ, for their own account. There are currently over 500 firms that act as NASDAQ Market Makers. One of the major differences between the NASDAQ Stock Market and other major markets in the U.S. is NASDAQ's structure of competing Market Makers. Each Market Maker competes for customer order flow by displaying buy and sell quotations for a guaranteed number of shares. Once an order is received, the Market Maker will immediately purchase for or sell from its own inventory, or seek the other side of the trade until it is executed, often in a matter of seconds. Market Order An order to buy or sell a stated amount of a security at the best price available at the time the order is received in the trading marketplace. Specialists Specialist firms are those securities firms which hold seats on national securities exchanges and are charged with maintaining orderly markets in the securities in which they have exclusive franchises. They buy securities from investors who want to sell and sell when investors want to buy. Stop An order that becomes a market order once the security has traded through the designated stop price. Buy stops are entered above the current ask price. If the price moves to or above the stop price, the order becomes a market order and will be executed at the current market price. This price may be higher or lower than the stop price. Sell stops are entered below the current market price. If the price moves to or below the stop price, the order becomes a market order and will be executed at the current market price. Stop Limit An order that becomes a limit order once the security trades at the designated stop price. A stop limit order instructs a broker to buy or sell at a specific price or better, but only after a given stop price has been reached or passed. It is a combination of a stop order and a limit order. These articles are for information and education purposes only. You will need to evaluate the merits and risks associated with relying on any information provided. Although this article may provide information relating to approaches to investing or types of securities and investments you might buy or sell, Wells Fargo and its affiliates are not providing investment recommendations, advice, or endorsements. Data have been obtained from what are considered to be reliable sources; however, their accuracy, completeness, or reliability cannot be guaranteed. Wells Fargo makes no warranties and bears no liability for your use of this information. The information made available to you is not intended, and should not be construed as legal, tax, or investment advice, or a legal opinion.
Recommended Content
Editors’ Picks
EUR/USD stays below 1.0550 ahead of US data
EUR/USD trades in the red below 1.0550 as investors await macroeconomic data releases from the US. The pair faces headwinds from risk-off flows due to rising geopolitical conflict between Russia and Ukraine and worries over the potential US tariffs on the EU.
GBP/USD pressured toward 1.2600, eyes on US data and Fedspeak
GBP/USD stays on the back foot and trades below 1.2650 on Thursday. The pair's underperformance could be attributed to a risk-aversion market environment. Traders stay cautious amid rife geopolitical tensions ahead of mid-tier US data and Fedspeak.
Gold extends gains beyond $2,660 amid rising geopolitical risks
Gold extends its bullish momentum further above $2,660 on Thursday. XAU/USD rises for the fourth straight day, sponsored by geopolitical risks stemming from the worsening Russia-Ukraine war. US data and Fedspeak are next in focus.
BTC hits an all-time high above $97,850, inches away from the $100K mark
Bitcoin hit a new all-time high of $97,852 on Thursday, and the technical outlook suggests a possible continuation of the rally to $100,000. BTC futures have surged past the $100,000 price mark on Deribit, and Lookonchain data shows whales are accumulating.
A new horizon: The economic outlook in a new leadership and policy era
The economic aftershocks of the COVID pandemic, which have dominated the economic landscape over the past few years, are steadily dissipating. These pandemic-induced economic effects are set to be largely supplanted by economic policy changes that are on the horizon in the United States.
Best Forex Brokers with Low Spreads
VERIFIED Low spreads are crucial for reducing trading costs. Explore top Forex brokers offering competitive spreads and high leverage. Compare options for EUR/USD, GBP/USD, USD/JPY, and Gold.